A classic stockmarket horror story for October: the Panic of 1907

Good morning – I’ve got another historical financial crash for your today. If you’re enjoying these, you might want to catch up on any you’ve missed. Ones we’ve already covered include the vanishing depression of 1920/21, the credit crunch of 1966, and the South Sea bubble. Now I’ll let you get back to today’s.

October is a vintage month for stock market crashes. All the best ones happen in October.

The crash of 1929 started in October. 1987 was October, too. And 2008 – well, it arguably kicked off in late September, but if you’d bought on 1 October that year, you’d still have been whimpering come the end of the month.   

A superstitious person might say “jinx”. A statistician might say “nonsense”.

I say, with the US stockmarket currently recording its most impressive record-breaking run since 1997, now looks the perfect time for us to share a scary story of Octobers gone by.

So today, in the latest of our weekly series on great financial disasters from history, let’s look at an October classic – the Panic of 1907…

How financial technology helped to create the Panic of 1907

The Panic of 1907 (also known as the Knickerbocker Crisis, for reasons we’ll see shortly) was “the first worldwide financial crisis of the 20th century”, notes the US Federal Reserve’s history website.  

As with many crashes, 1907 was part-assisted by a new financial technology. In this case, it was the trust (not to be confused with investment trusts, which helped cause 1929).

Trusts – like banks – took customer deposits. But unlike banks, they weren’t heavily involved in the payments system – they didn’t do much clearing of cheques, for example – so they didn’t carry as much cash.  

They also loaned short-term money out to equity market investors. As the Fed history website notes, the trusts would lend money to brokers. They didn’t require collateral, but the loan had to be repaid by the end of the business day.

Brokers would buy equities with the borrowed money. These would then be used as collateral for an overnight loan from a bank, which would be used to repay the loan from the trust. (Banks were unable to lend directly to the brokers because they were not allowed to make uncollateralised loans.)

In effect, trusts were liquidity providers. They took savings from customers, issued short-term loans, and made money from the spread between the two.

So that’s the technological backdrop. As for what had been going on in the run-up to October 1907 – the Dow Jones Industrial Average had peaked at 103 back in January 1906. An earthquake devastated San Francisco in April that year. By July 1906, the market was down nearly 20%. It rallied in the second half of the year somewhat, but continued to slip steadily during 1907, and by the end of September 1907, stocks had already fallen by nearly 25% from that January 1906 high.

So it was unquestionably a tricky time – similarly to the 2008 crisis, it didn’t come out of the blue. But the trigger for the actual panic came later that year, when a couple of speculators, F. Augustus Heinze and Charles W. Morse tried to corner the market in a copper mining company called United Copper.

In essence, they used money from the banks they owned or controlled to bet on the share price rising. They miscalculated, the scheme collapsed, and the banks they were associated with suffered runs as depositors bailed out. These bank runs were put to a stop by the New York Clearing House (basically a banking consortium that was there to maintain faith in the payments system).

However, More and Heinze were also associated with the Knickerbocker Trust. Depositors yanked their money out of it too. Like all trusts, it wasn’t part of the banking system, and so no one was willing to stand behind it and guarantee its customers’ deposits. JP Morgan was asked to help out. But without being convinced of the trust’s solvency, he wasn’t willing to help.

The run continued, and Knickerbocker collapsed on October 22. Panic ensued. Let’s say it was the Lehman Brothers moment of 1907. As Edwin Lefevre (journalist and author of Reminiscences of a Stock Operator, the biography of the stock trader Jesse Livermore) rather wonderfully put it in an article in 1908, “it is sad to want money and not get it. But to ask for your own money and not get it is the civilised man’s hell.”

How JP Morgan single-handedly saved the financial system

Depositors lined up outside other trusts. JP Morgan – realising that things were going pear-shaped – stepped in on October 24 to bail out the next-most vulnerable trust, Trust Company of America. But the damage was done – no one was willing to lend to anyone. The annualised interest rate on overnight loans had leaped from 9.5% to 100%.

Quoting from Reminiscences, Livermore – who made a fortune by shorting stocks through the crash – describes it as “a day I shall never forget… reports from the money crowd early indicated that borrowers would have to pay whatever the lenders saw fit to ask. There wouldn’t be enough money to go around.” In other words, it was a massive margin call.

Livermore himself, was sitting on massive paper profits. But it got to the point where he was concerned that he might be “unable to convert those profits into actual cash” if the panic went any further.

Fortunately for everyone involved, JP Morgan stepped in again. In effect, he took charge, kept the banks open and lending, and spent the next few weeks fire-fighting. The Dow Jones eventually bottomed in mid-November 1907, at 53 – a 50% drop from the start of 1906.   

In all, there are a lot of similarities to the crash of 2008 – a series of fudges and bailouts and near-misses and panics, largely facilitated by Morgan. (This later led to a great deal of scrutiny on Morgan as people started to question the wisdom of one man having that level of power, and of course, it amplified demands for the US to have a central bank, as Britain already did.)

The economy suffered badly too. If we hadn’t seen the Great Depression occur a few decades later, then we’d probably still talk about the aftermath of 1907 in similar tones. In all, there was a nasty recession between May 1907 and June 1908, in which unemployment rose from under 3% to 8%, imports collapsed by 26% and industrial production cratered.

The frustrations of being early

There’s a lot to learn from this particular crash. Like many of the others I’ve looked at, you could write a whole book and still be leaving stuff out.

But one small thing I wanted to pull out from the point of view of an individual investor, is an interesting quote from Livermore.

He made his first fortune in 1907 (he lost it pretty quickly afterwards, which was always Livermore’s big problem). But throughout 1906, he’d been bearish. And while the market did edge lower, it kept rallying and bouncing back and frustrating his expectations for an epic collapse.

In Reminiscences, he talks about the self-doubt that comes with being bearish and too early: “The first time I traded because of a crisis that was still to come, I found that I had been using a telescope. Between my first glimpse of the storm cloud and the time for cashing in on the big break, the stretch was evidently so much greater than I had thought, that I began to wonder whether I really saw what I thought I saw so clearly.”

It’s a useful lesson. Regardless of what’s going on around them, equity markets seem to be the financial equivalent of exuberant puppies. Always willing to expect the best from life.

Yet trying to predict the timing of any crash – despite the evidence all around of things going wrong – isn’t easy for even the best speculators.

That’s why, for most investors, diversification is a better approach than market timing. It’s not as much fun, true. But it won’t leave you broke and suicidal in your 60s – like Livermore – either.


Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *